High Volume Transport

Vital transport research to ensure accessible, affordable and climate friendly transport for all.

Policy options in third world urban public transport. Journal of Transport Management, 10 (8), 19-25


Publications with the same themes

View all

PDF content (text-only)

FYOURACRE, P R, 1986. policy options in third world public transport. ~journal'of Transport Management, 10 (8), 19-25. PiMc~y o~ptions, in-third: world urba'n '.p'ublic' transpo rt Overseas Unit Transport and Road Research Laboratory Crowthorne Berkshire United Kingdom POLICY OPTIONS IN THIRD WORLD. URBAN PUBLIC TRANSPORT - ~~~~~P. R. FOURACRE Principal Scientific Offcer, TRRL U. K. 1. Introduction.-- Between 1980-2000 much of the Urban transport policy in the Third World will world's urban expansion will take 'Place in--- less be increasingly directed to how best to fufil this developed regions (LDRs). UN forecasts indicate'*- ,growing demand using current and proposed pub- that during this period' the urban populationi in lic transport facilities. 'There will also be increased .settlements of more than 1 00,000 population will awareness of the possibilities for managing demand increase by over 1 00 per cent in LDRs as compared such that the burden on public transport facilities to only about 30 per cent in more developed re- is minimised. This paper looks at some of the gions (MDRs). Of the 57 cities expected to -have. policy options available for the development of populations in excess of' 5 .million 'by. the! year ~public. transport in the Third World, and assesses 2,000, 41 will be-in' the LDRs and118 will be -in--,likely. performance based largely on case study the very poorest C'ountries;'- where 'income per-capita material 'collected by the Overseas Unit of the is below $360'per annum.n . Transport and Road Research Laboratory. Much Currently the 340 million urban dwellers in cities t'his mate~ra relatres. toe India, butgins relvath to of over I million' population in. LDGs undertakemayohrcutisTepprbgnswha somehinglike4.5 0 mllio tris pe day ofbrief resume of the characteristics of public tran's- which p erhaps 3 040prcnwilbbysm -port systems currently operated in the Third World. form of public transport. The additional-- 600 million inhabitants expected to settle' infthese, and 2. Public Tramsor Characteristics. Public trans- similar size emerging cities by the end of. the cen- port in Third' World cities comes in a variety of. tury will add not only p roportionately to total trip physical and organisational forms. Conventio nal, making (assuming that-present rates of trip making standard public transport buses are currently being. per capita do n rot change appreciably,) but more operated in all cities of more than one million than projportionately to the. total person-k~ilometres'. 'populationbuthraefrfwrtamtrly-s generated. As cities expand in size and area., so or metro systems in use. in 1LDRs as compared to trip lengths will undoubtedly. increase and as a con- -'MDRs. For example, whereas 80 per cent of cities sequence. person-kilometres, which for -transport,, in MDRs of more than 2 million population have Operators is a more-relevant. expression of trans. metros, ornly one quarter Of similar sized cities in port demand. will increase at a faster rate than LDRs have such a facility.. The supply of conven- person trips.. tional buses is usually much smaller in the Third Thogh ersnalmotr'sd vhice onerhipzs '1 00,000 population in Third World cities as comn- likely to increase With 'some rise in reail incomes.:. - andconinu tobe oncntrtedin rba araspared to 50 to 80 buses per 100.000 population walking, cycling and public transport will remaininErpactes the most important modes of urban travel in the Third World. With 'increasing city size the burden Many cities have a large component of uncon- of commuter trios will inraigyfall upon ~pub- .j ventional or intermediate public transport (IPT) - lic transport as longer trip lengths will discourage-minibuses, converted utility vehicles,. rickshaws; walking and cycling as convenient alternatives. SO' Me cities of under one million population are Journal of Transport Mlanagement, Augwst 1986 1 XV7 1 1 . . 11 t --- . .^ . 19 solely dependent on these vehicles for the provi- sion of public trans port services. The contrast ,in institutional framework between the operators of conventional vehicles (sometimes referred to as the corporate sector of public transport) and IPT (the un~ncorporated. sector)~ is, sharpened by the profitability of .the two types; privately owned small fleets of IPT, often owner-driven, are pro- fitable whereas conventional buses, usually' organi- sed in large fleets and often run by local or cen- tral government, are seermingly difficult to main- tain as a .comnmerciail enterprise. The decline. in real fares, a, s ituation facing the cor porate sector 'in many Third World cities, only adds to the in- c.rease in derntnd for more, cheap public transport, which operators are unable to meet in a satisfac- tory way.. Operators Who cannot even cover their operating costs from fare'revenues are in a diffi- cult po`sition to fund the investments required to meet ever growing demands. IPT can be seen as a mecans of partially (or sub- stantially in manyi cases). filling the gaps in service that are, not provided by the corporate sector. Although vehicles classified as IPT are by no means homogeneous it is evident that the roles they play can be closely identified with those of~ either the classic taxi or stage-bus;- as operated in the. developed. world. In the taxi-like role the vehicle is hired. to carry the user from any point to any other point within the city, at a charge fixed by meter or bargaining. In the bus-like role the vehicle is. used on relatively fixed 'routes with .recognised .stopping points. along' the route;, fares .are charged for each person using the vehicle, and then rates are pre-set .for. given trip lengths. Fares are closely associated with 'the role being 'under- taken; vehicles used in the taxi-like role have relatively high charges while those used in. the 'bus-like role have relatively low charges. A comparative analysis of the o utput of public transport in 'medium size cities of India (Fouracr'e et al. 1981 ) suggests that in the majority of cases IPT accounts for at least 30 per cent of output (measured in terms of passengers carried) and may account for 80-90 per cent in a small number of cases. The importance of the role-- of IPT is not accognted for by city size: some larger Indian cities have as high a component of IPT as much smaller cities. Taking public transport as a whole, however, -it can be .generally stated that, its provisions incre ases with city Sizes. Conventional bus operators in the larger Indian cities play a significant part. in the movement of large' numbers of travellers. They have increased their capacity to meet the inevitable growth in demand for public trainsport services. However, there has been no. evidence of any economniesa of scale, and inflation has advanced unit costs of operation, while at the same time fares have been.. kept' artificially low by central and local govern- menits for socio-economic reasons. As a result, losses are being incurred on urban services which are either cross-subsidised from more profitable operations, such as inter-city routes, or are covered by government loans on; which interest'is payable. Little internally generated finance is available for investment in city bus operations ond operators must rely on whatever government support they can get, or employ the cast-off vehicles of the more profitable operations. Consequently. service levels either stagnate or deteriorate. In India the operating environment itself is often' a constraining factor on conventional bus opera- tions. In the old historic centres the road network is often tortuous and narrow. All forms of slow moving vehicles and street vendors use the limited network,.ca'using: chaotic traffic conditions. The newer parts 'of the ~city are often planned with little consideration o f transport requirements. Many people livin g on the periphery of cities. are those of low income; they have little paying capacity and yet 'mus't travel long, distances to work. Inevitably the bus operator is burdened with the task of 'providing cheap transport for these comn- muters. This compounds the problem, since the provision of cheap, long-distance transport en- courages more low-income groups to live out of the city in suburbs where ho use rents are also cheap. In summary the, problems likely to be encountered within the public transport sector of Third World cities broadly concern: -a dependence on public transport for means of travel; which. becomes more onerous as cities expand in size, the demand being largely generated by low-income commuters who have. little paying capacity. -poor financial performance of conventional bus fleets, usually associated with declining real fares and sometimes associated with in- efficient output or declining productivity. Journal of Transport Management, August 1986. 20 - a multiplicity of public transport modes in use, not all of which have clearly identified roles and many of which could possibly be deployed more, effectively. - insufficient investment. 3., Policy options. The options available to policy makers and transport operators fall broadly into one of three categories: - financial - technical *-institutional There is much ii~teraction between all three, but they are discussed individually below. 3.1 Financal policy options. Local and/or central governmnent ofe control:~ public transport fares and to, a lessers e xtteht.'siervce. ~levels (for example,. route allocation) 'directy. Costs may be influenced directly, through,. for example, tax, policy (both * as it affects input prices and as levied on opera- 'tional .output) and indirectly via the effects of - industrial and safety legislation on manning levels, minimum wage rates, vehicle up-keep, etc. Pro- ductivity, and hence costs, can also be directly influenced by traffic management measures which result in improved vehicle output. There is some evidence from operators of buses in the niationalised urban public transport sector in India that 'the cost increases they have experienced over the last ten years are totally attributable to increases in input prices: i.e. there has been no change in productivity over that period. Though 'productivity has not deteriorated in absolute terms. the corporate sector rarely bears comparison with private, small-fleet operators of similar vehicles, being used in similar conditions. For example, in. Delhi the difference 'in costs per unit of output is as much as 20 per cent in favour of the private operator. This difference may largely be accounted for by labour practices, the larger comnpanies, which are more in the public eye, being constrained by labour and safety legislation controlling driver hours and vehicle standards. Interestingly, there are also cost differences within the nationalised sector between large and small. fleet' operators operating similar vehicles but in different operat- ing conditions,' i.e. large and 'small cities. The largest fleet operators in India, operating in' the large metropolitan cities of more than 1 million population. have costs per vehicle km some 30 per cent (and more) higher than the small er fleet. used in correspondingly smaller cities. (To put this in some perspective the largest operator has a fleet size about 70 times greater than the smallest). In the western world these difference's might be ascribed to the lower productivity of vehicles in bigger cities due. to more congestion (Webster, 1983) and perhaps greater problems of staff recruitment experienced. in. these condi- tions. (It is geaerally. accepted that there are few economies or diseconornies of scale within the bus. industry). However, in. India vehicle productivity' in urban conditions is generally highest in larger' cities being typ-ically 200-220 kms per vehicle-day. .as against 1 70-200 kmns per vehicle-oday in sma'ller"'* cities. A closer examination of. the cost components which contribute most to the difference in total costs indicates that capital costs are. primarily responsible; the large companies pay significantly more in in teriest and depreciation payments, per unit of output. (The reasons for this are not clear from available data, but could be attributable to differences in investment policy -for example, encouraging more modern fleets in larger cities - or, in some cases, results from the cumulative effects of deficit financing, itself the effect of low fares). E xpenditure per unit of output on other cost items like manpower, fuel and spares is largely uninfluenced by fleet size. Labour productivity could undoubtedly, be im- proved within the nationalised sector following trends adopted in the western world such as, for example, one-man-operation of buses. However. the associated. need for expesvseial techno- logies (eg automatic doors) may make such an. exercise prohibitive. Furthermore, buses in the Third World are much more highly loaded, with average load factors between 70 and 80 per cent, compared with 20 to 30 per cent in the UK, making the drivers' task more onerous. Neither is there the same pre ssure on labour costs, where. typically only 40 per cent of costs are attributable- to this source as againsit 70 per cent in the UK. The argument over differences in costs between private and nationalised operators is often confused with other arguments about the optimum size of firm and optimum size of bus. In general smaller vehicles will 'be more iexpensive to run per seat kilomnetre, all other things being equal. But they. mity well be more profitable than large buses to operate. even with similar fare structures; fare Journal of. Tramso~ bbManaeent, August 1986 22 1 leakage is less, fare concessions are fewer and the service can be more easily tailored to fluctuations in demand (both spatially and temporally) to achieve consistently high load factors. It is unlikely. however, that mninibuses' are. as is sometim es implied, the panacea to urban transport problems. They have a role to play, but the demands of high .density commuter movements. require, a, high capacity transport system which does not have the external congestion costs that a large fleet of minibuses might incur. In general vehicle output in the Third World is very .tigh. with vehicle' being run continually throughout the day. Annual output may be of the order of 60,000 km as against 45,000 for a bus used in urban conditions in the developed world. Bus priority rmeasures do not guarantee improvements in vehicle productivity, the time .savings having to be quite substantial before more trips can be undertaken or fewer buses employed. The main benefit may be a more reliable anrd speedy service, with perhaps tighter headways.. Where significant changes in overall bus speeds result, the fuel consumption may be improved - for example, if bus speeds in Delhi could be improved overall by 1 0 per cent then bus operating costs would be reduced by about- 1 or 2 percent. fuel being a major cost component (as much as 20 or 30 'Per cent of total costs) in Third World urban bus operations. Another way of improving vehicle productivit~y is to provide express or limited-stop services, though this may be at the expense of passenger throughput. An express bus service in use in Hy- derabad was achieving 1 0 per cent greater vehicle output than ordinary stage services. but Was gross- mng 20 per cent less revenue. (Maunder and Foura- cre, 1983). This example highlights one important area where there is vast scope for improvement in bus operations: planning and management sup- port services. Resources could be used more effec- tively through closer monitoring of route, depot and workshop performance. Cost -benefit techniques could be used to demonstrate the net worth of alternative development strategies including the be- nefit derived from subsidies. The oft-heard cry of operators both in the pri- vate and nationalised sectors is that fare levels are not kept in line with increasing costs. In India there is, some evidence from the nationalised sec- torwhic kees better recordstsupr this. For example, bus fare levels in Delhi in 1981 'were. some 30 per cent lower in real terms than they had been seven years earlier. Private operators of IPT may be able'to resolve the problem on an unilateral (though illegal) basis by bargaining their services and rates with users prior to a. journey. Even so, from time to time there are open con- frontations between these operators, usually acting through their trade associations, and local govern- menit on the level of fares.' The-implicit justification for the control of fares is that the urban poor, who form a substantial part of public transport demand, are a captive market and they do not have the 'resources to, pay the full cost of their travel, It is also often. levelled against operators that the real pressure on fares comes from declining productivity standards, ra- ther than rising input prices, and that they should rationalise their operations before demanding fare increases. As noted earlier, such accusations may not be fair. A cheap fares. policy can be regressive in that. large numbers of travellers who benefit could well afford to pay more for travel. The growth in char- ter bus operations, which has taken place in cities: like Delhi, is largely accounted for by users of' stage buses who have been prepared to pay more for the higher quality service provided by the: charter bus. A policy of more selective relief for the urban poor-- whilst desirable, would probably be extremely difficult to administer. Some of the. concessionary travel which public transport ope- rators provide (and the costs of which they bear). is anomalous. In many instances students are able to travel at absurdly cheap rates. Revenues 'lost' on these concessions should be recognised openly as a form 'of subsidy and reimbursed by local government,' paricularly where students are travel- ling during peak periods. Services and fares might profitably' be geared more dlosely to different sectors of the market: in many instances the 'role of IPT can be seen in this light, providing a higher quality service at higher rates. Some corporate sector operators have introduced parallel high quality services at pre- mium fares, but, for a variety of reasons, not al- ways with, muich financial success . (Maunder and Fouracre, 1983). This again points to a much grea- ter emphasis on service planning based on proper .market research techniques. One problem of fragmenting the market in this way is the loss of network advantage- the ease, of interchange between routes and services is much. .Journal, of Transport Managenut, Augw 1986 reduced.~ How important this is clearly depends on many factors, but it is likel~y to be felt. more in larger cities which may involve mpore comnplex travel patterns. 3.2 Technical policy options. Technological change is. continually being directed towards 'an improvement in vehicle performance and/or a reduction in operating costs. The auto-rickshaw' of S. E. Asia can 'be seen as the logical development of the. more traditional cycle and' hanti-rickshaws, which it may, well replacie completely in years to come. There will be little pressure, as, noted earlier, to introduce technology which improves labour pro- ductivity. Apart from the abundance of cheap la- bour and the need to provide employment, the more advanced technologies required need expen- sive skilled .maintenance labour and facilities. Also it must be accepted that driver skills in the Third World leave much to. be desired, and that the greater capital investment would be exposed to the same high level of accident risk as is. the much cheaper equipment in current use. Perhaps the major debate concerning technical advance in public transport in larger Third World cities is about how beat to provide for high volume passenger movement on major corridors, at mini- mum cost. A few cities in LDRs have. metros - notably Mexico City, Sao Paulo, Rio de Janeiro and Peking -while several other cities (eg Cairo, Calcutta and Baghdad) are currently investing in heavy mass. transit systems and many others are discussing the possibility. Yet others (eg Tunis) are considering light Rapid Tragsit (LRT) or trolley bus systems (eg Delhi). Metros cost two *to three times as much as an LRT to build (£20 to £40 million per kin) and can be slow to construct, particularly in central areas where extensive tunnelling is necessary. On oper ational costs they can. compete with existing' bus systems and LRT only at very high loadings. If user and non-user costs (te economic costs) are included in the comparison then metros are likely to be far more cost-effective in relation to LRT and existing bus sc hemoes, particulairly in very con- gested areas. What is 'not often appreciated, how- ever, is the extent to which capacity could be increased for an existing bus system. Reserved lanes (eg Bangkok), segregated tracks (eg Curi-- tiba) and operational improvements (eg the Co- monor system of bus convoys in Sao Paulo) are all *techniques which can be used to increase ef- fective passenger throughput on buses. In Bang- kok the bus lanes are achieving loadings of 250 conventional buses per hour, together with as many as 1 00 minibuses per hour (Milrler, 1982). Total, passenger loadings could, therefore be well in ex- cess of 20,000 per lane hour, which is well within the range of figures usually quoted for metros of between 10-40,000 per track hour. (Lehner, 1975).' The reasons why cities have opted for the high- cost metro are not entireJlar clear. It may be that planners have been persuaded that the metro is the only technical 'solution to moving large volumes of people quickly and effectively. It may also be that economic considerations outweigh financial im- plications, though if this is the case it is unfor- tunate for the operators *that the economic argu- ments get forgotten when the need arises for sub- sides to keep the system functioning. And undoub- tedly subsidies will be required, because to charge financially based fares would divorce the metro system from its obvious role of catering to mass- movements of low-income wage earners. (It is es- timated that the cost per place km on metros in ',Third World cities could be as much as 80 per cent higher than on' buses). Both Bangkok and Singapore have witnessed much contentious debate about the relative merits of a bus system or a metro, with the latter currently in -greatest favour. Energy considerations may have some influence on the direction of public transport developments. For example, the availability of cheap, hydro- generated electricity may make a tr'olley-bus system an attractive alternative to diesel-powered buses. In national terms, the savings* in energy irrports are likely to be small. Even so, it is well to remem- ber. that despite the current depressed state of the oil market many observers predict continuing long term price rises in. petroleum products. 3.3 Institutional policy changes. There are perhaps two key issues of institutional policy. One concerns the extent to which the public transport sector should be controlled by local government and whether fewer restrictions would promote a more efficient and effective service. The other issue concerns the extent to which demand can be managed, through institutional techniques, in order to reduce the burden on supply. On the question of regulatory policy, most authorities would agree the need. for quality licensing, but few would agree about the need for Journal of. Transport Management, August 1986 223 quantity licensing. The debate seems intractable with no clear evidence for either the need or otherwise; more often than not the debate becomes highly, politicise'd. and perhaps the pragmatic approach would be to accept that local politics will be the main. arbiter of what system will be adopted. However, it is worth. making a few points. There is no guarantee that dc-regulation opens up' the market to all-comers. Very often, trade asso- ciationis or cartels (of owners or drivers) take up the role of regulation, so as to avoid the risks of cut-throat competition. There is no certainty that such cartels would. show any. sense of responsibility towards community needs, nor, indeed, woul]d they be accountable in any way to the community. Dc-regulation is often seen'as a means of intro- ducing a greater sense of commercialisation into existing nationalised operators and recent experi- ence. from the UK tends to confirm that. this can happen. There has been a positive reaction on the part of nationalised operators to the threat from greater competition with a move to introduce better services at more competitive prices and with --more comprehensive 'marketing.' The in- adequacy of management support facilities in Third World operations (noted earlier) might hinder such positive response there. This sh~ould not be seen as an argument against de-regulation. rather that this particular objective of the policy. might not be fulfilled in these conditions. One suggestion that is receiving increasing -attention and seems to have some merit, is for 'local authorities to specify the public transport :service they require, for which tenders are then requested from prospective operators. This so- .called -supply-side- competition (Quarmby, 1984) 'Would allow operators to concentrate solely on .Providing their services cost-effectively (to meet *the specification), leaving the problems of how to :specify ser vices (including social and unremunera- tive) to local government who would hopefully reflect community needs. Demand management is the policy option which is open to local authorities largely as a result of their control' over land-use development. Other instruments. like the staggering of office hours may, have marginal effects on congestion levels; perhaps of more relevance is the segragation of school and ~ffice hours so that students are not travelling during peak hours. The interaction between city and 'transport development is by no means clearly under stood. The effects are two-way and probably of a long- term nature. The provision of cheap public trans- port or large investments in transport infrastruc- ture may be just as significant to structural change in the city as planned land-use development. The latter may. itself, depend critically, on co-ordina-, tioni with transport developments for its success. In too many cases transport has been developed in an inefficient way in order to solve accessibility problems created by unilateral devel opments in land-use; for exam~ple,~ .the development. of residential township (usually for the urban poor)' isolated from employment opportunities and other ,amnenities. Even so, it would be wrong to assume that an integrated approach to land-use and transport development will solve all such problems. Siting industry and workers in close proximity. for instance. may reduce transport demands in the short-term; as time goes on. however the travel patterns of individual, households will change, for a variety of reasons, and particularly so in larger cities where other employment opportunities exist and where the structure of industry and the urban economy may be changing quite rapidly. This would militate against making investments in 'fixed' systems like metros, It seems inevitable however that there will be a continuing need to provide for the large-scale transport of commuters along recognised corridors during limited periods of the day. The pragmatic approach might be to recognise this fact and to develop. along these corridors, providing industrial and employment opportunities along their length. 4. Concluding remarks. Having reviewed some of the policy options. available, it. must be said that there can be no single approach to transport .development which can or should be adopted. .Transport policies obviously have to be planned in -the light of local city development objectives. operating circumstances and available resources. It is quite eviden t that different cities have approached the problem of providing for transport demand in different ways and there is some evidence of a broad correlation between certain characteristics of the city and :its transport system. However, the mechanism of interaction between the two needs much greater understanding, if only to avoid the (frequently) inevitable result of creating the long-term problems through solving immediate transport demand problems. 24 ~~~~~~~Jourawl of Traumpi Mangeent, Augun 1986 24 5. Acknowledgements. The work described in this paper forms part of the programme of the Overseas Unit (Unit Head:,J. S. Yerrell) of the Transport and Road Research Laboratory and the paper is published by permission of the Director. 6. References Fouracre P. 'R., D. A. C. Maunder,' M. G1.Pathak and C. H. Rao ( 1981) Public transport supply., in Indian citii4..~ Department of the Environment. Departm ent of Transport, TRR1L Report LR 1018. Crowthorne, UK (Transport and Road Research Laboratory). Lehner F. S. (1975). light rail and rapid transit, Light rail transit special report 161. .US Transportation Research Board, National. Research Council. National Academ-y of Sciences. Washington. 1975. Marler. N. W. (1982). The performance of high-flow bus lanes in Bangkok. Department of the Environment, Department of Trans- port. TRRL, Report SR 723. Crowthorne, UK (Tra nsport and Road Research Labora- tory). Maunder D. A. C. and P. R. Fouracre (1983). Specialised bus services in three Third World. cities. Department of the Environment, Department of Transport, TRRL Report SR 81 1, Crowthorne, UK (Transport and Road Research Laboratory). Quarmby D. A. (1984). Public transport opera- tions.'Highways and Transportation. April 1984.1 'Webster F. W. (1983). The importance of cost minimisation in public transport opera- tions. Department of the Environment, Department of Transport, TRRL Report SR 766. Crowthorne. UK (Transport and Road Research Laboratory). SO J~wa of Trasot aaemua~ Au~w 1986